Employment

From Citizendium
Revision as of 05:52, 18 August 2008 by imported>Nick Gardner (→‎The demand for labour)
Jump to navigation Jump to search

In everyday use the concept of employment encompasses a variety of productive activities but it has narrower connotations in the fields of law, statistics, and economics. The behaviour of the market for employment has significant implications for the performance of the economy, and employment practices have significant sociological implications.

Definitions

The term employment is used colloquially to refer to any human activity devoted to the production of goods and services. In legal terms it has the narrower meaning of a contractual arrangement that gives an employer some measure of control over the activities of an employee, and in national statistics it includes self-employment but excludes unpaid activities and activities in the “shadow economy” that are concealed from the authorities[1].

Employment legislation

Employment legislation imposes statutory requirements upon the relations between employers and employees concerning matters that include working hours, health and safety at work, minimum wage rates, dismissal restrictions and redundancy payments. The levels of employee protection provided by the legislation vary from country to country [2].

Employment statistics

For statistical purposes the population is divided into three categories:

  • the employed population;
  • the unemployed population; and,
  • the economically inactive population.

The first two categories together comprise the working population, consisting of those people of working age who are available for employment (including, in principle, workers in the shadow economy). The third category includes those falling outside the chosen working age definition, the disabled, and those not seeking work for other reasons (sometimes referred to as discouraged workers). It also includes those who provide unpaid services to households. The percentage of the population of working age who are members of the working population is termed the activity rate.

National employment statistics [3] are compiled from employer and household surveys [4], according to internationally-agreed principles [5], but differing in practice from country to country, making comparisons hazardous. The composition of the labour force is normally recorded by sex, industry and occupation [6].

Employment economics

The labour market

The labour market occupies a special place in the interactive network of markets that make up an economy, and it has special implications for the welfare of its people. It affects productive and economic efficiency by its allocation of human resources among alternative activities, and it influences the way that people choose between consumption and leisure. It is made up of a large number of different markets that can be categorised in a variety of ways. Dual labour market theory distinguishes between a "primary segment" of employment for sustained periods such as is referred to as a career, and a "secondary segment" of temporary employment in short-term jobs [7], and a distinction is sometimes made between external labour markets and those that are internal to employing organisations [8].

Most labour markets differ significantly from the perfect market [9] of economic theory. The labour supply is often far from homogeneous, the information available to the parties is usually far from complete, and some degree of market power is often present. The "Walrassian auctioneer" [10] is not an apt analogy for the market process and the deal that is arrived at has the characteristics of an "incomplete contract" [11] in that the responsibilities of employer and employee are not exhaustively specified. For employment that requires training, the existence of an interval between a decision to supply and its implementation introduces additional uncertainties. Those departures from the ideal model affect the process by which the supply of labour is reconciled with its demand.

The supply of labour

The motive to seek employment may be expected to be determined by the wage rate on offer and upon personal preferences as between employment and other activities. (In this context the alternative to employment is referred to as “leisure”, although in fact it includes childcare, housework and voluntary work). Two effects are at work. On the one hand, an increase in the income that is offered can increase the attractiveness of employment as the result of the “substitution effect” (so called because it induces a substitution in which leisure is sacrificed for the sake of getting employment). On the other hand, additional income tends to motivate an increase in the consumption of leisure (as well as of other benefits) , creating what is termed an “income effect”. Eventually, as income increases, the “income effect” can be expected to outweigh the substitution effect, so that further income increases reduce the motive to seek employment [12]. The aggregate labour supply to a closed economy is affected by the age structure of the population and its participation rate, and the participation rate is affected in turn by the income and substitution effects of wage rate changes and by fertility rates and life expectancy changes. [13]. In open economies, migration may also have a significant influence. Thus the supply of labour may be expected, first to increase with each increase in the wage rate offered, but eventually to fall in response to further increases.

The demand for labour

The demand for labour derives solely from the demand for the products on which it can be employed. The demand for a particular skill by a hypothetical sole employer of that skill would depend, not only upon the demand for the product on which it is to be employed, but also upon substitutes for that skill such as investment in automation. Such an employer may be expected to increase its employment provided that the net cost of doing so would be less than the consequent increase in revenue. Since increases in the revenue from the firm’s product may be expected to depend upon its cost of production, the firm’s demand for the skill may be expect to rise with reduction in the cost of employing it, and vice versa. (In most industries, that effect may also be a consequence of the short-term operation of the law of diminishing returns.) The total demand for that skill by a market of competing employers at a given wage rate would be the sum of the numbers that each would employ at that rate. In a competitive market, each employer may be expected to take the going rate (as determined by the process of bringing supply into line with demand) as given, and adjust employment accordingly.

Economic implications

The sociology of employment

References

  1. For estimates of the magnitude of the shadow economy, see that paragraph in the article on gross domestic product
  2. NATLEX" (database of national labour and social security legislation) International Labour Organization 2008
  3. LABORSTA, International Labour Organization database of national economic statistics
  4. Database of Labour Force Surveys, International Labour Organization 2008
  5. Standards and Guidelines for economic statistics,
  6. International Standard Classification of Occupations
  7. Glenn Cain : The Challenge of the Segmented Labor Hypothesis to Orthodox Theory, Journal of Economic Literature 1985
  8. Peter Doeringer and Michael Piore: Internal Labor Markets and Manpower Adjustments, D C Heath & Co 1971
  9. The concept of a perfect market is defined in the article entitled "market"
  10. For an explanation of the Walrassian auctioneer see "The auctionneer analogy" in the article on supply and demand
  11. For an account of the economics of incomplete contracts see Eric Brousseau and Jean-Michel Glachant: The Economics of Contracts: Theories and Applications , Cambridge University Press, 2002.
  12. Income and substitution effects are also discussed in the paragraph on “price effects" in the article on supply and demand
  13. . David Bloom, David Canning, Günther Fink and Jocelyn. Finlay : Demographic Change, Institutional Settings and the Labor Supply , Harvard UP 2007