History of economic thought

From Citizendium
Revision as of 19:28, 18 October 2007 by imported>Matt Mahlmann (added subpage)
Jump to navigation Jump to search
This article has a Citable Version.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Timelines [?]
 
This editable Main Article has an approved citable version (see its Citable Version subpage). While we have done conscientious work, we cannot guarantee that this Main Article, or its citable version, is wholly free of mistakes. By helping to improve this editable Main Article, you will help the process of generating a new, improved citable version.

Modern economic thought is generally considered to have originated in the late eighteenth century with the work of David Hume and Adam Smith, and their campaign against the prevailing policy of mercantilism. Earlier approaches, including the development of mercantilism, are described in the article on the History of pre-classical economic thought. The nineteenth and twentieth centuries saw major developments in the methodology and scope of economic theory, and the process of development continues.

Nineteenth century economists applied deductive reasoning to axioms considered to be self-evident, and to simplifying assumptions which were thought to capture the essential features of economic activity. That methodology yielded concepts such as elasticity and utility, tools such as marginal analysis, and theorems such as the law of comparative costs. An extension of the relationships governing transactions between consumers and producers was considered to provide all that was necessary to understand the behaviour of the national economy.

The development, in the early 20th century, of systems of economic statistics enabled economists to use inductive reasoning to test theoretical findings against observed economic behaviour, and to develop new theories. Independently of that change, the concept emerged of the national economy as a closed interactive system. Such a system was found to behave in ways that could not be derived by aggregating the behaviour of its components. Analysis of the new concept provided explanations of recessions, unemployment and inflation that were not previously available. The application of empirical data and inductive reasoning to the new concept enabled those theories to be refined, and led to the development of forecasting models that could be used as tools of economic management.

The late 20th and early 21st centuries have seen further theoretical and empirical refinements and significant advances in the techniques of economic management.

Mercantilism

The prevailing economic policy for some centuries before Adam Smith's time had been founded upon the belief that a nation's wealth consisted mainly of the gold and silver that it possessed. In accordance with that belief, governments generally intervened in commerce to subsidise exports so as to promote inflows of gold and to and restrict imports in order to discourage an outflow. That, briefly, was the policy that Adam Smith termed Mercantilism.

The contribution of David Hume

The Scottish philosopher, David Hume was an early exponent of what was later known as monetary economics. He contested the mercantilist thesis, partly on the grounds that an inflow of money would cause inflation [1] , but also on the grounds that nations would benefit from the international specialisation and division of labour that would result from the introduction of free trade. More generally, he argued that all government intervention in commerce tended to obstruct economic progress by hampering the normal division of labour.

The Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations

A major advance in the development of economics ocurred with the publication in 1776 of Adam Smith's An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations [2]

Classical economics

Major economists following David Smith included Jean-Baptiste Say[3] , Robert Malthus and David Ricardo[4]. Ricardo's model laid the basis for the classical models that became the mainstream in economic theory for the whole of the 19th century.

Malthus

Malthus (1766-1834) is most famous for his "Essay on the Principle of Population" [5] where he formulated the theory that population expanded at a geometric rate (or exponentially) while food production could only increase arithmetically. At a certain point, the population increase would outrun the food supply, and result in general misery. Malthusian models were a major inspirations for Charles Darwin's theory of Natural Selection (1859). Malthusian pessimism regarding depleting resources has become a major themes of the environmental movement.

Ricardo

David Ricardo (1772-1823) set the theoretical fundamentals of the classical model. Ricardo's system depended on the idea of the marginal productivity of land, and was the inventor of the "marginal" concept. His idea was that the value of agricultural products (and hence food) was based on the amount of labour required to produce on the least fertile parcel of land. Hence the "Law of diminishing marginal productivity". Landlords owning land that was more fertile, and who could produce more for a given amount of land, obtained "rents". His conclusion was that the future was in buying land. He, of course, did not predict the tremendous increase in technology and productive capacity brought about by the capitalist system.

Ricardo was also responsible for the idea of comparative advantage in international trade His classic example was between wine and clothing and England and Portugal. Portugal was more efficient than England in producing both cloth and wine, but England had a comparative advantage in cloth production. He showed that it would be advantageous for Portugal to specialize in wine and England to specialize in cloth, and to trade with each other. This resulted in more wine and cloth all around.

Marxism

Karl Marx[6] is the most famous of Ricardo's followers. Writing during the mid-19th century, Karl Marx saw capitalism as an evolutionary phase in economic development. He believed that capitalism was inherently exploitation of the workers, who really produced all wealth, He predicted capitalism would ultimately destroy itself and be succeeded by a socialist system without private property. Marx had little impact on the development of pure economic theory because his theory added little to Ricardo's, though he came to different conclusions. Marx placed little emphasis on the diminishing marginal productivity of land, but more importance on the falling rate of profit. To Marx, capitalist competition would lead to the impoverishment of the "proletariat" or working class and a falling rate of profit. The ultimate resolution would be a communist revolution with the workers seizing power. Soon after the death of Marx, a Marxian school of economics [7] emerged under the leadership of Marx's inner circle of companions and co-writers, notably Friedrich Engels[8] and Karl Kautsky [9].

Institutional schools

German historicism was represented by Werner Sombart (1863-1941)[10], and historical sociologist Max Weber (1864-1920). In his classic The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism (1905) Weber stressed the importance of Protestant value systems in forming a capitalist mindset and rational outlook toward calculating the future.[11] Vilfredo Pareto (1848-1923) made numerous contributions to the study of inequality, showing that in modern societies wealth distributions are heavily skewed in an exponential manner (so that a few people are very rich rich, and most are poor).[12] In addition Pareto defined "Pareto optimality," which is widely used in welfare economics and game theory. A distribution of wealth is "Pareto optimal" if no one can be made better off without someone else being made worse off. A standard theorem is that a perfectly competitive markets create distributions of wealth that are Pareto optimal.[13]

The most widely read American economist was Thorstein Veblen (1857-1929)[14], a witty commentator on capitalism, the leisure class, and conspicuous consumption. More pedantic but more influential was John R. Commons (1862-1945), who stressed legal frameworks, historical development and practical collection of statistics; he ignored theoretical mathematical models.[15] Commons dominated economics at the University of Wisconsin,[16] where his disciples preached strong government regulation and intervention in the economy, and designed the Social Security pension system that went into effect in 1935. John Kenneth Galbraith was a major spokesman for liberalism and the planned economy, as he poked fun at capitalism and promoted the New Deal Coalition.


The main development of Business Cycle Theory, led by Wesley Clair Mitchell (1874-1948) and sponsored by the National Bureau of Economic Research from the 1920s into the 21st century, used massive amounts of statistical data, but at first avoided macroeconomic theory.[17] Important exponents included two economists who headed the Federal Reserve System, Arthur Burns (1904-1987)[18] and Alan Greenspan (1926- )[19].

Leonid Vitalyevich Kantorovich (1912-1986), and Wassily Leontief (1906-1999) developed the "input-output" technique; it was used mostly in planned and developing economies for determining the levels of resources necessary to produce according to a given plan.[20]

The marginalist revolution

In the 1870s, three economists became responsible for what is called the "Marginalist Revolution" [21] - William Stanley Jevons [22] , Carl Menger [23] and Léon Walras [24] . They, independently of each other, developed a new theory of value based on utility. The three are responsible for the concept of marginal utility [25] , and the derivation of a downward sloping demand curve [26]. The Marginalist Revolution would eventually put an end to the The Classical Scholl [27] and the era of the Neoclassical School [28], which lasts to today, began. This made possible the logical analysis of the "Producers's Decision" [29] or how and why "producer" transforms factors of production into finished goods.


Alfred Marshall dominated economics in Britain from the 1870s well into the 20th century. Among his major contributions to economic theory was his explanation that the price mechanism operates by the interplay of supply and demand, replacing the contention of earlier economists that price is determined by the cost of supply. He was responsible for developing numerous concepts still used in economics, such as elasticity of demand and consumers' surplus, as well as the diagrams used to explain them.

Marshall's work was refined and further developed, and continues to be extended to this day. Neoclassical economists have built magistral logical edifice into a "Production Function" [30] that rival Newtonian mechanics in completeness and rigour. The basis of neo-classical economics is maximisation under constraint, and this constantly involves the "marginal concept" [31]. The tools developed by economists are even now beginning to be used by other social sciences such as anthropology, sociology and even psychology.

International trade theory

Bertil Ohlin, (1899-1979), professor of economics at the Stockholm School of Economics (1929-65) and longtime leader of the Swedish Liberal party shared the 1977 Nobel Prize for economics with British theorist James E. Meade (1907-1995) for their "pathbreaking contribution to the theory of international trade and international capital movements."[32]

The Keynesian revolution

Keynesianism, introduced by Cambridge (England) economist John Maynard Keynes in 1936, and revised by John Hicks, dominated mainstream economic thought from 1936 to the early 1970s. Keynes' ideas on the causes of unemployment revolutionalized macroeconomic theory and profoundly altered government's involvement in the economy. Instead of micromanagement of prices and factories, the Keynesian model told governments to regulate the overall supply and demand, through taxation and budget deficits or surpluses. In the 1970s economists became increasingly critical of Keynesian ideas, because it could not handle stagflation (the real-life combination of high unemplyment and high inflation), and because because of problems with the micro-foundations regardiung issues such as the "consumption function." The leading British Keynesians were Sir John Hicks (1904-1989) and Richard Stone (1913-1991)[33] The leading American Keynesians were Alvin Hansen (1887-1975) at Harvard, Paul Samuleson (1915- ) and Franco Modigliani (1918- ) at MIT, and James Tobin (1918-2005) at Yale.[34] Milton Friedman (1912-2006) at the University of Chicago was the leading critic of Keynesianism, though his own alternative theory of monetarism was found wanting in practice.

The monetarist "counterrevolution"

While the Keynesian-Neoclassical synthesis took over the profession, an unregenerate rearguard of neo-classical economists centred at the University of Chicago continued to exist. See Chicago School of Economics They never accepted the possibility of involuntary unemployment or the desirability of government intervention to ensure full employment, and strongly believed in the virtues of markets and laissez-faire. The most famous economist of the Chicago School is Milton Friedman. Originally a Keynesian and a strong supporter of unemployment programs (which employed Friedman and his wife during the Great Depression), he began attacking the consumption function component of the New Deal model in the 1950s. He was mainly responsible for what is known as the Monetarist counterrevolution of the 1970s. In 1968 he announced the Keynesian model was liable to "stagflation" and could not be used to "fine tune" the economy. The prediction proved accurate in the 1970s with the failure of Keynesian models to explain or resolve the "stagflation" of the 1970s, (which combined high unemployment and high inflation), the free market prescriptions of monetarism became a serious alternative. They were espoused by many governments in the 1980's (Reagan in the US, Thatcher in the UK, Mulroney in Canada), and, perhaps more importantly, by the central banks of most industrialized countries. In practice, however, monetarism was too inflexible to set policy and all the central banks stopped using it by the 1990s.

The Chicago School of Microeconomics

The Chicago School of Economics not only challenged established theories in macroeconomics, they pioneered the expansion of microeconomics to include antitrust and many unexpected topics, such as marriage and divorce, criminal behavior, and slavery. The main tool was price theory as developed by Ronald Coase (1910- ), George Stigler (1911-1991) and Gary Becker (1930 - ).[35]

Thematic schools

Thematic Schools are specialty areas especially: Business Cycle Theory, Demography, Econometrics, Imperfect Competition, Economic Development, Uncertainty and Information, Game Theory and Finance Theory.

Economics subdisciplines

Modern economic theory is divided in two main branches: Microeconomics which is concerned with the actions of "individual economic agents" and Macroeconomics which studies the aggregate economy.


External links

See also

References

  1. David Hume Essays, Moral and Political, 1742, Vol2 Of the Balance of Trade (published by Liberty Fund 1985)
  2. Adam Smith. The Wealth of the Nations. Modern Library, 2000
  3. Jean-Baptiste Say
  4. David Ricardo
  5. "Essay on the Principle of Population"
  6. Karl Marx
  7. Marxian school of economics]
  8. Friedrich Engels
  9. Karl Kautsky
  10. Jürgen G. Backhaus, ed. Werner Sombart (1863-1941): Social Scientist. (1996), 3 vols.
  11. Stephen Turner, ed., The Cambridge Companion to Weber (2000) excerpt and text search
  12. H. O. A. Wold and P. Whittle, "A Model Explaining the Pareto Distribution of Wealth" Econometrica, Vol. 25, No. 4 (Oct., 1957), pp. 591-595 in JSTOR
  13. Vijay K. Mathur, "How Well Do We Know Pareto Optimality?" Journal of Economic Education22#2 (1991) pp 172-78 online edition. But see also Joseph E. Stiglitz, "Pareto Optimality and Competition," The Journal of Finance, Vol. 36, No. 2, (May, 1981), pp. 235-251 in JSTOR; and Alan T. Peacock and Charles K. Rowley, "Pareto Optimality and the Political Economy of Liberalism" The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 80, No. 3, Part 1 (May - Jun., 1972), pp. 476-490 in JSTOR
  14. John Patrick Diggins, Thorstein Veblen (1999) excerpt and text search
  15. Malcolm Rutherford, "Institutional Economics: Then and Now," The Journal of Economic Perspectives 15#3 (2001), pp. 173-194 in JSTOR
  16. Malcolm Rutherford, "Wisconsin Institutionalism: John R. Commons and his Students." Labor History 47 (2006): 161-188. online edition
  17. Wesley C. Mitchell and Arthur F. Burns, Measuring Business Cycles (1946)
  18. Malcolm Rutherford, "'Who's afraid of Arthur Burns?' the NBER and the foundations Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 27#2 (June 2005) pp 109 - 139
  19. Alan Greenspan, The Age of Turbulence: Adventures in a New World (2007)
  20. Wahid (2002) ch 8, 11
  21. The Marginalist Revolution
  22. William Stanley JEVONS, 1835-1882
  23. Carl MENGER, 1841-1921
  24. Marie Esprit Léon WALRAS (1834-1910)
  25. Marginal Utility Animated graph
  26. Demand Functions and Demand Curves
  27. Classical School
  28. Neoclassical School
  29. "Producers's Decision"
  30. "Production Function"
  31. Marginal Utility and Optimization
  32. Wahid (2002) ch 14-15
  33. Wahid (2002) ch 7, 23
  34. Wahid (2002) ch 4, 20, 24
  35. Wahid (2002) ch 21, 32, 33

Bibliography

  • Cate, T., Colander, D., and Harcourt,g. Encyclopedia of Keynesian Economics. 1997
  • Coats, A. W. Bob The Development of Economics in Western Europe since 1945 1999 online edition
  • Dorfman, Joseph. The Economic Mind in American Civilization, 5 vol 1947-1959, thorough coverage down to 1933.
  • Eatwell, John et al eds. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics 3 vol 1998; 2nd edition scheduled 2008, edited by Steven Durlauf and Lawrence Blume
  • Ekelund, Robert B., and Robert F. Hebert. A History of Economic Theory and Method (2007)
  • Haney, Lewis H., Ph.D. History of economic thought: a critical account of the origin and development of the economic theories of the leading thinkers in the leading nations. 1920. online edition
  • Marshall, Alfred., "The Growth of Economic Science" in Principles of Economics (Appendix B), Macmillan 1890.
  • Medema, Steven G., and Warren J. Samuels. Historians of Economics and Economic Thought: The Construction of Disciplinary Memory 2001 online edition
  • Negishi, T. History of Economic Theory (1989) excerpt and text search
  • Robbins, Lionel et al. A History of Economic Thought (2000) excerpt and text search
  • Roncaglia, Alessandro. The Wealth of Ideas: A History of Economic Thought (2006) excerpt and text search
  • Samuels, Warren, John Davis, and Jeff Biddle, eds. A Companion to the History of Economic Thought. Blackwell (2003) excerpt and text search
  • Samuels, Warren J. Histories of Economic Thought (2003) [excerpt and text search
  • Schumpeter, Joseph A., History of Economic Analysis, (1954, 1996) excerpt and online search
  • Wahid, Abu N. M. Frontiers of Economics: Nobel Laureates of the Twentieth Century 2002 online edition
  • Yonay, Yuval P. The Struggle over the Soul of Economics: Institutionalist and Neoclassical Economists in America between the Wars 1998 online edition